TUNISIA AND SYRIA ARMY IN THE REGIME CHANGE
I. Introduction and Context
The Arab World has recently experienced unprecedented popular
mobilization that changed the political landscape of the region. From Tunisia
to Syria, Arab societies have demanded political and economic freedom in a
context of economic crisis. A crucial aspect of Arab transitions lies in the
speed at which supposedly strong leaders were overthrown. Regime changes in
Tunisia and Egypt showed the relative weaknesses of these governments dictated
by Ben Ali and Moubarak, respectively. These two regimes had maintained the
illusion that their power is rooted in all strata of the population, with an
unquestionable loyalty of the security apparatus and de facto, of the pressured
population. Ben Ali’s authoritarian regime successfully maintained the myth of
a performing state until the 2008 food crisis and the global economic crisis.
As Beatrice Hibou analyses in her book, Tunisia under Ben Ali could be defined
as a “policing state”. That is a country in which there is an absolute
oversight of the population. The taxi sector constitutes a good example of how
the regime used the population as “watchdogs” to denounce criticism towards the
regime. The force of obedience established by Ben Ali’s regime is not about
police force or a strong regime. It is all the more about the control of
economic policies to pressure certain groups of the population, such as taxi
drivers, to keep an eye on potential threats (Hibou, 2006). However, this
control has showed its limits in recent years, as the illusion of a performing
state vanished.
First, the food crisis of 2008 resulted in unprecedented protests in the
Gafsa Mining Basin. Expending geographically to the whole region, riots
gathered demonstrators from different classes such as miners, students,
unemployed and lawyers. Slogans in the streets directly criticized a corrupted
regime and its inability to counter unemployment and inequality (Cloutier,
2012). Police forces started a violent repression that was unsuccessful in
stopping the revolt. The army intervened thereafter, killing 3 protesters and
injuring 10 others. Demonstrators immediately abandoned the struggle against
the regime after the army’s intervention. Second, the suicide of the street vendor Mohamed Bouazizi on 17 December
2010 detonated anger in the populace. In two weeks, demonstrations spread
nationally, affecting all major cities in Tunisia. While police forces
struggled to contain protesters in
different regions, the army protected strategic infrastructure and official
buildings. On 12 January 2011, the regime declared a curfew and the army
was deployed in cities’ streets. After the population consistently refused to
respect this curfew, the army was assigned to repress those who disrespect the
law with the obligation to open fire. Military forces, led by its army chief of
staff, decided to reject the Tunisian regime’s order to repress protesters
(Murphy, 2011). Ben Ali escaped from his residence only two days after the
army’s noncompliance. This crucial decision has mostly been omitted by the
literature on regime change in the Arab World. This article acknowledges the
importance of pressure from below to explain Ben Ali’s fall. However, popular
mobilizations do not constitute a sufficient factor to explain the Tunisian’s rapid
political transition. This article aims to elucidate a paradox in Tunisia’s
regime change; namely, how such a perceived strong regime, with an absolute
oversight of its population, broke down in the first few week of year 2011.
Without neglecting the importance of the popular pressure, we argue that the
army played a central role in the fall of Ben Ali. Why did the Tunisian army
refused Ben Ali’s order to open fire at the demonstrators in 2011? What are the
implications of such a decision? This paper is the first attempt to compare two
consecutives events in which the army has decided to open fire at its own
population, namely the 2008 protests in the Gafsa region and the massive
revolutionary protests of early 2011. What is the rational thinking behind such
decisions? Did the army have enough of the generalized corrupted regime
organized around Ben Ali’s personality? Or, instead, did it choose to back the 2011 protests
because it was simply better-off for doing so? This paper will tackle questions
on what consequences this decision had on the key actors of the uprising,
namely Ben Ali, the demonstrators and foreign allies.
We find that the army was better-off to refuse Ben Ali’s order at this
point in time because the probability that Ben Ali leaves power was high
enough. We will show how this decision has been a turning point in the Tunisian
uprising by altering motivations of the key players. After analyzing the
evolution of the civil-military relationships, an extended model of game theory
will be introduced to depict the interactions between Ben Ali’s regime and the
army. This model focuses on one decisive aspect; namely the decision of the
army to accept or refuse Ben Ali’s order to shoot at protesters. We compare two
major demonstrations in which the army had the choice to shoot at people: the
Revolt of the Gafsa Mining Basin in 2008 and the uprising of 2011 that lead to
the Tunisian transition.
II. Literature Review
Most recent studies explained that unprecedented pressure from below
caused the end of Ben Ali’s regime (Joffe, 2011; Jdey. 2012; Bellin, 2012;
Kuhn, 2012; Campante
and Chor, 2012; Aleya-Sghaier, 2012; Allal and Geisser, 2011-2012; Illan,
2012; El- Khawas, 2012). An interesting approach brings the middle class as an
important feature of a democratic society and the process of democratization
(Leventoglu, 2013). Critics of this precondition have argued that transitions
in Latin American countries saw actors from the middle class supported coups.
Nevertheless, this seems to be relevant to understand the Arab Spring. Tunisia,
for instance, known as a middle-class society, has seen popular mobilization
from every strata of the society to overthrown the dictator Ben Ali. In Egypt,
the Muslim Brotherhood constituted a very organized opposition force, which
gathered not only the poor but also democratic and secular young Egyptians
(Way, 2011). The middle class is clearly an important precondition to the
extension of popular protests that started Arab transitions but is certainly not
necessary to explain variations of transitions outcomes in the Arab World.
The occurrence of democratic transitions may also be explained by the
strategic interactions of principal agents, namely the elites and the civil
society.
Joffe G. (2011) argues that Ben Ali’s fall was due to the organization of
the population after spontaneous
demonstration and emphasizes on the role of the Tunisian Labor Union UGTT.
Bellin E. (2012) focuses on the “power of contagion” and collective action from the population to put pressure
on the regime. While Kuhn R. (2012) sees a direct link between the improvements of human
development and social mobilization, Campante F. R. and Chor D (2012) show how
the level of education of Tunisians affected the demand for economic
opportunities. Economic crisis and the lack of job opportunities were,
according to them, major to explain the national protests.
Although pressure from below was determinant to explain regime change in
the Arab World and more precisely, in Tunisia, it does not seem to be
sufficient to fully understand the rapidity of the Tunisian transition. A few
articles have tried to identify the rupture between elites, and especially the
role of the army to trigger change in Tunisia (Way, 2011; Barany, 2012; Gause,
2011; Sorenson, 2012; Dalacoura, 2012).
Barany Z. (2012) argues that the lack of support from the army was
necessary to the success of popular mobilization. He explains that the regime’s
lack of consideration, the disinclination of corruption organized by the
executive power as well as the non- political status of a professional army
justified the non-willingness of the Tunisian troops to repress its own people.
However, even though tensions between the
Tunisian army and the regime have affected the army’s decision to refuse
Ben Ali’s order to open fire on the protesters, Barany Z. (2012) omits the
army’s decision to open fire on the protesters during the 2008 protest of
Gafsa. Thus the disdain and the status of the Tunisian army towards the regime
is not sufficient to explain the army’s decision. Gause G. (2011) argues that the army has
taken the opportunity to risk not to
back the regime in order to play a more important role after the transition (Dalacoura
K., 2012). This argument has also shown its limitations since the Tunisian army
has not been actively part of the political debate unlike the Egyptian army
that organized a coup early July 2013. The literature on the role of the army
in Ben Ali’s fall do not take into account historical and institutional factors
to explain the reasons held by the army to not back Ben Ali’s regime. In
addition to that, it appears that these
studies mainly used a descriptive analysis instead of an explanatory
demonstration.
Instead, I find that the evolution of the civil-military relationships as
well as the high institutionalization of the Tunisian army constituted the
preconditions in the ability of the army to make a rational decision to back
street protesters. Before demonstrating why the army refused the order to shoot
at protesters – using an extended model of game theory – I will analyze key
historical and institutional factors to explain current contentious
relationships as well as the relative independency of the army to Ben Ali’s regime.
III. Analysis: the role of the Tunisian army in Ben Ali’s fall
3.1. The Evolution of the civil-military relationships
The uniqueness of Tunisia’s experience in Arab transitions is mainly due
to the special features of the military
forces in the Tunisian society.
Ben Ali ruled Tunisia for 25 years through his party, the “Rassemblement
constitutionnel démocratique” (RCD). About 2 million citizens (20% of the
population) were official members of his party. Most opposition parties were
controlled and cooperated with the RCD. Threats from any oppositional
organizations were forced into exile such as the powerful Islamist party.
Through his personal security forces as well as the growing influence of his
step family on the Tunisian economy, Ben Ali built a powerful system of control
in Tunisia. In December 2010, when protests erupted with the suicide of
Mohammed Bouazizi in Sidi Bouzeid, popular protests quickly spread in the
country. Demonstrators demanded the end of corruption and political
liberalization reforms at first. However, the regime relied on his security
forces, the police as well as the army to contain national protests. While the
Tunisian police and Ben Ali’s personal forces opened fire on the demonstrators,
the army deployed its troops into Tunisia’s key locations without intervening
actively. In fact, newspapers in Tunisia notified that the army had a
surprisingly sympathetic relationship with street protesters and actively
helped them (Schraeder and Redissi (2011). How can we explain such a behavior
of military forces, looking at Tunisia’s history and institutions?
Overall, the evolution of military forces in Tunisia from the 1980’s is
characterized by its professionalization
as well as its depoliticization. Ben Ali as well as his predecessor Habib
Bourgiba were opposed to the integration of the army into the political arena.
Ben Ali was himself a General from the army that took power in a bloodless coup
d’état in 1987. Tunisia can thus be described as an autocratic officer-
politician regimes, in which a former military officer is head of state
though converted into a civilian
politician. This differs from a military-ruled regime as the army doesn’t have
a direct influence on politics (Appendix 1). Despite Ben Ali’s military
background, he has constantly limited the political power of the Tunisian army by fear of a military coup. It is also worth noticing that the so-called ‘silent’ or
‘invisible’ army does not have economic power (Anderson, 2011), unlike
the Egyptian Army that led to a military
regime. This further explains the lack of political ambition of the military
forces.
It is necessary to consider the degree of institutionalization as a
potential factor of regime change triggered by the army’s decision power
(Bellin, 2004). Bellin argues that the more institutionalize military forces
are, the more likely they will support political reforms and disconnect from
political elites’ interests. Because the security apparatus is based on
meritocracy and performance bounded by a clear set of rules, ties with the
regime are not as embedded as in patrimonial relationships. High
institutionalization of the military forces thus indicates that they are
relatively committed to defend national interest overall instead of certain
groups, and clearly identify themselves as an entity completely separated from
the central political power. Instead, we can expect military forces based on
patrimonialism (Institutionalism = Low in Appendix: Table 1) in a tribally
dependent monarchy to oppose popular support because their strong ties with the
regime. The Tunisian army forces became a highly professional force which did
not interfere with political issues and were overall free of corruption
(Lutterbeck, 2013). The high degree of institutionalization of the Tunisian
army is therefore associated with a certain independency towards Ben Ali’s
regime. Interestingly, Tunisia and Egypt offers two examples of military forces
supporting the will of its people. With relatively institutionalized military
forces, the army chose to disengage with the regime and join the opposition.
This is in line with Bellin’s suggestions; namely that highly institutionalized
armies are more likely to support popular demand because they are independent
to the regime’s interest, professionals and mainly follows national interests.
With a good understanding of the army forces and its power, Ben Ali found
necessary to weaken the army’s power to not endure a similar fate than the
previous regime (Murphy, 2011). To dissuade the population from contesting his
power, Ben Ali based his power on a strong police apparatus, reaching 120 000
policemen in 2010, instead of on a national army. Military expenditures were
very low compared to other countries (1.5% of GDP) in the region and the number
of officers had not ceased to decrease until the Tunisian army became the
smallest army in North Africa. Tunisian troops amounted to only 35 000 soldiers
in 2010 and were underequipped (IISS, 2010). Distrust between these two actors
reached a peak in April 2002, when “thirteen
Tunisian military officers, including the army chief of staff Brigadier
General Abdelaziz Skik, were killed in a helicopter crash” (BBC, 2002). The
army never believed this tragedy to be an accident but rather a strategic calculation
by Ben Ali’s regime, which was suspicious and threatened by the militaries.
Overall, the military forces in Tunisia were highly independent from the regime
in power, highly institutionalized and had contentious relationships with the
regime. These historical and institutional features of the Tunisian army are
the preconditions of the ability of the army to actively support the street
protests in 2011 by refusing to open fire on its own people and demanded Ben
Ali and his family to leave the country.
I have shown the relative independent and contentious relationships
between the army and Ben Ali’s regime over time. However, to explain Ben Ali’s
fall, it is necessary to focus on a crucial single point in time, which will be
analyzed by a model of game theory, to explain the strategic interactions
between the army and the regime.
3.2 The army’s decision to support protesters: a model of Game theory
This paper emphasizes on the role of the army in regime transitions and,
more specifically, on the strategic interactions between the Tunisian
militaries and Ben Ali’s regime to
explain the fall of Ben Ali in 2011. The methodological goal of this article is
to bring a more detailed and explanatory analysis of the interactions between
regime elites, using game theory.
3.2.1 Approach and Methodology
The extended model of game theory used in this paper to explain the
Tunisian transitions is mainly inspired by Przeworski’s model in Democracy and
the Market (Przeworski, 1991) as well as an extension of this model presented
by Blaydes and Lo in their article “One man, one vote, one time? A model of
democratization in the
Middle East” (Blaydes and Lo, 2012)1.
![]() |
1 Blayde and Lo (2012) presents their methodology as follow: we extend a
canonical model of political transition developed by Adam Przeworski in
Democracy and the Market (Przeworski, 1991) to include the possibility of two
types of uncertainty. The first – discussed in the original Przeworski
conceptualization – is uncertainty on the part of civil society regarding the
willingness of regime liberalizers to repress; the second involves the
uncertainty of regime liberalizers regarding civil society’s commitment to democracy”.
Przeworski demonstrates that a regime transition is a result of a choices
and strategies between political and economic elites in a context of
uncertainty in a given society.
Tunisia has seen this context of uncertainty with a period of high
unemployment and economic crisis from 2008.
Przeworski claims that a transition may happen when elite groups have an incentive to deviate
from the status quo and impose a regime change, notably because of the
non-establishment of strong ties between a regime and key elites in a society.
Democracy emerges from a bargaining between elites in a society, and, more
precisely, when a strong unity between competing democratic elites is created
against the authoritarian regime.
In his model, at the specific moment when an authoritarian regime is
considering political liberalization, Przeworski analyzes the choices and
strategies of the “proto- liberalizers” in a given authoritarian regime and key
actors within the civil society.
Blaydes and Lo extended Przeworski’s model and applied it to political
transitions in the Middle East (Blaydes and Lo , 2012). These authors decided
to test two assumptions made by Przeworski by focusing on the Middle Eastern
democratic transitions. First, they integrated uncertainty or incomplete
information, as the civil society may not know to what extent an authoritarian
regime prefers repression over democratic transition. Second, they also cast
doubt on the assumed commitment of the
civil society to democratic principles in the Middle Eastern countries. Their
results suggest that democracy cannot emerge when the regime’s repressive
capacity is too low. Second, they
emphasize the importance
of uncertainty and
beliefs which essentially determine the type of regime
post-transition2. The model introduced in this paper aims to analyze the strategic
interactions between the Tunisian army and Ben Ali’s regime, resulting in a
regime transition. Our extended model mainly draws on the previous work of
Przeworski and Blaydes and Lo described above.
2 Blaydes and Lo (2012) presented their argument as follow: “The model
solution suggests a number of key findings. The first is that the existence of
uncertainty is key to the possibility for democratic transition. Second,
transition to democracy is only possible when the repressive capacity of a
regime exceeds a certain threshold. Given these conditions, democracy occurs
when regime liberalizers who prefer democracy to a narrowed dictatorship
interact with a civil society that will honor democratic principles”.
This study acknowledges Blaydes and Lo’s contribution to Przeworski’s
model of transitions in the sense that uncertainty is a crucial determinant
that must be taken into account to study regime transitions. However, while
Blaydes and Lo assumed imperfect information of the civil society to explain
the resulting type of regime, our analysis will take into account uncertainty
and, more precisely, asymmetry of information between Tunisian elites, namely
Ben Ali and the militaries. This does not mean that the demonstrators had a
complete understanding of the balance of power during the 2011 uprisings. As
discussed in the last part of this paper, the Tunisian transition shows the
crucial impact of strategic behaviors chosen by the elites to signal to the
population the current balance of power, solving the incomplete information of
the civil society before Ben Ali’s escape to Saudi Arabia.
The methodology of this paper substantially differs from most studies on
the Arab Spring because of the strong focus of our analysis. Most authors have
chosen to compare regime transitions in Arab countries and the role of the army
in different transition outcomes. There is, by nature, a lack of focus in these
analyzes. This results in a misconception of the political economy and inherent
structural differences across countries. For these reasons, we focus our
analysis only on the Tunisian transition, drawing on both historical
intuitionalism and strategic interactions of key actors in Tunisia.
Unlike Przeworski and Blaydes and Lo’s model, one can notice that this
study does not seek to predict the types of regimes which could result from the
transition. Too many factors are in play and, as the Egyptian case has shown
with the overthrown of previous President Morsi by the army in 2013, even
short-term prediction in an uncertain context is quasi-impossible.
Considering the Tunisian case only, the main questions this paper tries
to answer is: Why did the army refused Ben Ali’s order to open fire on its own
population? How did this decision affect key actors of the Tunisian transition?
Finally, how to explain that this decision resulted in Ben Ali’s fall?
3.2.2 Model and Equilibrium
This sequential model of game theory analyzes the strategic interactions
between two key players of the Tunisian transition; namely Ben Ali’s regime and
the army. I will draw on two major popular threats – on the regime to explain
the army’s decision to accept
orders from the
regime to repress
protesters. We will then
show the
implications of the army’s decision on
protest outcomes3.
3.2.2.1
Actions and Order of Play
First, Ben Ali’s regime responds to popular protests in 2008 and 2011 by
ordering the army to repress demonstrators (Repress?) or to keep the status quo (SQ). In the two situations I analyze, the status quo can be described as high
popular mobilizations in the streets. Police forces are trying to maintain
order and stop protests using violent
methods. The army is present in key locations but does not intervene directly.
Due to the two advanced protests of 2008 and 2011 and the police repression,
this model assumes that Ben Ali’s regime is not able to make credible political
liberalization reforms4. Second, the army will accept (Accept) or reject Ben Ali’s order to
repress demonstrators. Given the contentious relationships with the regime and
the army’s relative independence, this decision to follow orders will be made
depending on the probability that Ben Ali’s regime survives, thus on the
repressive capacity of the regime as well as the strength of the civil society
that protests in the streets.
Finally, Ben Ali’s regime remains in power (Stay) with a probability p if the status quo remains, a
probability q if the army accepts to
repress protesters and a probability r if
the army does not follow Ben Ali’s order to open fire on demonstrators. We identified four potential outcomes in the sequential game presented
below (Figure 1).While these scenarios help us to understand the army’s
decision to refuse to open fire at its population, this article focuses on the
decisive aspect of whether Ben Ali leaves power:
![]() |
3 Other security chiefs, notably from the police and the president personal
security, have played a role in influencing Ben Ali’s decisions. However, we
assume here that the army was the decisive actor that made the difference in
Ben Ali’s escape.
4 Even though
Ben Ali has made enormous concessions the day before his escape, it cannot be
said that
the population could take Ben Ali’s potential willingness to reform as a
credible commitment. Interestingly, Ben Ali’s concessions seems to share many
similarities with Ceausescu’s last speech, in which he made the same types of
concessions to his people.
1. Stronger Dictatorship (STRONG): If the
Tunisian army accepts to shoot at its population and Ben Ali stays in power,
the bloodbath’s success will certainly reinforce the complicity and the mutual
interests between the regime and the army.
2. Civil (WAR): If the army accepts to open fire
and Ben Ali is overthrown in the long-run, the situation is likely to be highly
unstable leading to division within the Tunisian society. Although the term of
civil war is discussable, we might expect armed conflicts between the
pro-regime and the anti-regime close to the Lybian repression of 2011 or the
current civil war in Syria. We assume here that the Ben Ali’s departure will
inevitably occur in the long-run.
3. Weakened Dictatorship (WEAK): The
scenario in which the army refuses Ben Ali’s order and Ben Ali stays in power
will weaken the regime’s power. The desertion of the military’s forces might be
seen as a strong signal that the regime’s security forces as well as national
elites are divided.
4. Regime Transition (TRANS): This
scenario depicts what actually happened in Tunisia, i.e. a regime transition
supported by a coalition between the army and the Tunisian people. If the army
refuses Ben Ali’s order and Ben Ali leaves power, a regime transition is
expected even though there is a high uncertainty on the type of regime.
However, we only focus on the Tunisian regime transition itself, namely whether
Ben Ali stays or leave power.
Figure 1. A sequential game between Ben Ali and the Army
3.2.2.2
Payoffs
Ben Ali’s payoff is determined by the probabilities that Ben Ali stays in
power (p, q and r) relative to the utility of each actor when he stays in
power. p, q and r describe these
probabilities which depends on the army’s decision to repress (Repress?) or not
(Status Quo).
This model assumes that Ben Ali’s payoffs equal zero, if the status quo
prevails. Although this assumption follows conventional practices, the fact
that Ben Ali would or should stay passive is discussable in this type of
political instability. However, the regime would be willing to keep the status
quo because it could reinforce its repressive capacity due to the provision of
defense weaponry and training provided by foreign allies. As a result, while
the strength of the civil society may grow marginally, it might be all the more
true for the repressive capacity of the regime’s security apparatus. Overall,
Ben Ali gets a payoff of zero because the balance of power between the regime
and protests may not change substantially if the status quo is kept. In line
with Przeworski’s liberalization model, the following equation gives a good
picture of these variations when the status quo remains:
p = Repressive Force / Civil Society strengths5
The army’s payoff is also based on the probability that Ben Ali remains
in power relative to the army’s expected utility when Ben Ali stays in power.
However, this utility is conditional on whether military forces accepts or
rejects Ben Ali’s order to repress demonstrators. The army’s payoff equals 0 if
the status quo remains, which describes the situation in which the army
occupies strategic points of the Tunisian territory but do not take direct
action either in favour of or against the demonstrators.
3.2.2.3 Actor’s preferences
Ben Ali obviously prefers to stay in power rather than being overthrown.
However, the regime is certainly
better-off if the transition is done peacefully than through an armed rebellion
or a civil war. Therefore, he will get a payoff of -2 if the outcome is a
![]() |
5 In his model, Przeworski assumes that protesters start to get organized
only after the regime has engaged with political liberalization. It appears not
to be the case in the 2011 Arab uprisings, including the Tunisian experience.
civil war (WAR) and -1 if a peaceful transition prevails (TRANS).
Intuitively, he will prefer to stay in power conditional on the acceptance of
the army to repress the demonstrators (STRONG) rather than suffering from a
contentious situation with the military’s force. Therefore, a stronger
government will give Ben Ali a payoff of 2 and a payoff of 1 if the game
results in a weaken government (WEAK). The status quo, as explained above,
equals zero since the spread of demonstrations might be counterbalanced by, for
instance, the reception of new weapons and equipment sent Tunisian’s allies or
the weakening of the street protesters.
We assume here that the army is indifferent between opening fire on the
demonstrators conditional on Ben Ali to stay in power (STRONG) and refusing to
open fire conditional on the regime to leave power (TRANS). In both cases, the
army will get a payoff of 2 because we assume that their payoff is completely
determined by the identity of the regime
post- protests.
We will assume that they are indifferent between the two outcomes in
which they make a wrong prediction, namely in the scenario of a civil war (WAR)
and of a weakened Government (WEAK), and will get a payoff of -1. While this assumption is indeed
discussable, it does not change the final equilibrium and we only use it in our
analysis as a matter of simplicity. The matrix presented below (Table 1) describes Ben Ali and the army’s preferences in the
sequential game. The choice of these specific numbers has been decided for
simplification, notably to improve graphical clarity. Results do not change
substantially when actors’ preferences vary.

3.2.2.4
Possible outcomes of the theoretical
model
Actors’ preferences and payoff are conditional on the probability that
Ben Ali stays in power. Therefore, this section aims to take into account the
probabilities p, q and r to compute the threshold at which Ben Ali is
indifferent between keeping the status quo (SQ) and repressing the population
(Repress?), as well as the threshold at which the army is indifferent between
following and refusing Ben Ali’s order to repress the population. The
probability r is greater than q as the regime’s repressive capacity
increases when militaries make use of their weapons. In other words, there is a
greater chance that the regime stays longer in power if the army accepts to
shoot at protesters, even though this doesn’t essentially determines the
outcome, namely whether Ben Ali will fall. Thus: q
r. The probability p, q and r are given by Ben Ali’s
repressive capacity relative to
the strength of
civil society (Blaydes
and Lo, 2011);
i.e. p, q and r = 


Given the actors’ preferences as well as the order of the p, q and r, we
are now able to compute the four possible equilibrium of this game.
First, the equilibrium (SQ; Accept) describes the situation in which Ben
Ali chooses to keep the status quo while
the army decides to accept to open fire. This condition is given by the
following two inequalities: + (1 – q)
As Ben Ali gets a payoff of zero if the status quo remains (SQ), 2 if he
represses the population, the army accepts the order and he remains in power
(STRONG) and -2 if the army accepts to repress the population but Ben Ali
leaves (WAR), the previous equation becomes:


In other words, we can say that Ben Ali’s regime will choose the status
quo when the probability that he leaves power is equal or lower than a half.
·
Following the
same logic of calculation, we have:

Second, there is an equilibrium (SQ; Reject) when Ben Ali chooses to keep
the status quo while the army decides to reject Ben Ali’s order to shoot at the
demonstrators. This situation is given by the following inequalities:
·

· 



Third, the equilibrium (Repress; Accept) exists when Ben Ali’s regime
decides to repress its people and the army accepts this order. The following
inequalities define this situation:
![]() |


· 

In this
situation, we get: 


Fourth, (Repress; Reject) is an equilibrium when Ben Ali’s regime make
the order to repress the demonstrators and the army rejects Ben Ali’s order.
This situation must satisfy the following inequalities:
![]() |


· 



Table 2. Equilibria and
conditions of four potential decisional outcomes
Equilibria
|
Conditions
|
(SQ; Accept)
|
(
![]() ![]() |
(SQ; Reject)
|
(
![]() ![]() |
(Repress;
Accept)
|
(
![]() ![]() |
(Repress;
Reject)
|
(
![]() ![]() |
3.2.2.5 Results
Figure 2 describes our results and contains information about the four
scenarios discussed above as well as the probabilities of Ben Ali to stay in
power. Our results are presented below the straight line r = q, as we assumed
previously that r is surely smaller than q, namely that the probability that
the regime stays longer in power if the army accepts to shoot at protesters (q)
is greater than this same probability conditional on the army to reject the order to open fire (r). We will focus
on the area in which q≥
, as we want to compare the 2008 and 2010 demonstrations. We can simply
notice

here that there is no equilibrium (SQ; Accept). This might look surprising at first
glance.
However, it suggests that no situation exists where the army would accept
to repress the demonstrators and Ben Ali would prefer the status quo. In other
words, whenever the army is ready to accept to open fire on the streets, Ben
Ali will prefer to order a repression (Repress; Accept).
Figure 2.
Equilibria of the game relative to the probabilities q and r
|
More specifically,
when q ≥
and q
, Ben Ali’s regime will choose the equilibrium (Repress; Accept), namely
the dashed area in Figure 2.


In other words, when the probability that Ben Ali stays in power
conditional on the army accepting to follow orders is high enough and the
likelihood that the regime stays in power conditional on the army refusing
orders is high enough, Ben Ali decides to order a repression of the population
and the army accept this order.
The 2008 Gafsa
protest can be represented within this dashed triangle.
Proposition 2: When q is high and
bounded by a low probability r, Ben Ali’s
regime will order to repress
its population but the army will reject this order.
More specifically,
when q ≥
and q
, Ben Ali’s regime will choose the equilibrium (Repress; Reject), namely the dotted area in Figure 2.


In other words, when the probability that Ben Ali stays in power
conditional on the army accepting to follow orders is high enough and the
likelihood that the regime
stays in power conditional on the army refusing orders is low enough, Ben
Ali decides to order a repression of the population but the army rejects this
order.
The uprising
of 2010, leading to a regime change, is represented within this triangle.
Due to incomplete information, Ben Ali’s decision to order the shooting
is not perfectly based on the army’s expected utility because he doesn’t know
at which points the army will refuse to the order to open fire. In other words,
Ben Ali has vague information about the
limit at which the army will accept to shoot. For simplification, we assume
here that Ben Ali’s decision to order a repression is based on an expectation
that the army will follow his order. The army, however, follows its preferred
expected utility given that we assume that it has complete information about
Ben Ali’s expected utility. Even though the Tunisian army has been seen as a
‘weak’ or even an ‘invisible’ actor in Tunisian affairs, it remains a key
actor, notably because of this asymmetry of information that the army can take
advantage of. The decision of the two
actors during the two different protests was highly influenced by asymmetry of
information giving an advantage to the army. Because Ben Ali didn’t expect the
army to consider rejecting the regime’s order, he only took his decision
according to the probability that he stays in power when the army intervenes.
This decision was likely to be the most effective to stay in power during the
2008 Gafsa protests. In fact, we can see that the army repressed the population
because the probability that the regime stays in power, even if the army had
refused to open fire, is too high.
Therefore, the regime made the “best” decision to remain in power.
However, the uprising of 2010 demonstrates that asymmetry of information
between the regime and the army was crucial to determine a regime transition.
In our case, asymmetry of information allows the army to have a large
control of the final equilibria because the Generals have more information than
Ben Ali’s regime. During the 2011 uprising, the probability of Ben Ali
remaining in power was below the line q
=
r + 1 because the spread of the
population reached a high level that is close to the point where the
probability of Ben Ali falling is more likely (towards q =
and r = 0). The balance of power between Ben Ali’s
repressive force and the strength of the
civil society is such that the army prefers to reject Ben Ali’s order to shoot
at the population.


Let’s suppose that we have complete information. Ben Ali would have
integrated the probability of the army to reject the order into his
calculations. This would have substantially changed our equilibria and thus the
outcome of the game. A smaller area would have represented the equilibrium
representing Ben Ali’s decision to repress his people and the army to reject
this order. Ben Ali would have preferred the status quo than to give the order
to shoot. Therefore, we can speculate that Ben Ali would have been able to stay
longer in power with complete information.
However, this equilibrium has not reflected Ben Ali’s decision, mainly
because of asymmetry of information that destabilized the regime. In reality,
Ben Ali gave the order to shoot and the army refused because he has incomplete
information about the army’s preferences and payoffs. It is thus suggested that
Ben Ali would have been better off and stay longer in power by choosing to keep
the status quo. Critics of these interpretations may emerge because of the idea
that it is easier to draw lessons after that the transitions actually happened.
No one was able to predict such a fast regime change because of the illusion of
domination that Ben Ali projected on his population and external actors.
However, we have attempted to look at the strategic interactions of the elite’s
behaviors to explain the Tunisian transition. The next part of this paper will
give a detailed analysis of the crucial interactions and strategic behaviors
that explain how the Tunisian army’s decision to reject Ben Ali’s order has
been crucial to push Ben Ali out of the country.
IV. Implications
4.1 Despite tensions, why has the Tunisian army never attempted a coup?
Barany Z. (2012) proposed to explain why the army has never taken actions
against the regime can explain why the army has never taken substantive actions
to overthrown the power in place. Ben Ali’s regime was careful in limiting the
army’s power in terms of numbers, budget allocation and the scope of its role
and its responsibility. Therefore, the army was largely overshadowed by more
influential forces in the political economy of Tunisia. Ben Ali’s government
conscientiously used the police and
other security agencies to secure and control its population. Another reason
that can reveal the lack of ambition from the militaries to take power is the regime’s decision to send a significant number of officers to the
United States in order to attend trainings and programs. The regime
strategically made sure that the army stays away from political concerns and be
distracted by other concerns than politics (Barany Z. 2012).
The weakness of the army’s political power in Tunisia constitutes an
important factor to explain why the militaries have never attempted to
overthrown Ben Ali’s regime. It is also argued here that the likelihood of Ben Ali’s regime to stay in
power was always too high for the army to attempt any action against the regime.
Beatrice Hibou (2006) explains how Ben Ali’s regime was involved in every
strata of the Tunisian society and reinforced its power by satisfying key
elites and civil society organizations. As the long as this long-term
equilibrium sustained, the army had no feasible actions that could be
undertaken against the regime even though tensions have always been present.
The 2008 regional protests of Gafsa demonstrated that the army was
willing to back the regime and commit crime on its own population. The spread
of the demonstrations was, unlike the 2011 uprisings, not as big of a threat
for the regime. The army had no choice but to act severely against the Tunisian
manners for the political power. Referring to the extended game presented
above, we can observe that the probability that Ben Ali will remain in power
was too high for the army to take the risk to take the population’s side. Acting as such would
have meant for them to accept retaliations from the regime, which is not in
their interests. Timing was also crucial. The expansion of protests to the
whole region was quick and Ben Ali’s order to the army came when the balance of
power on the field was clearly in the regime’s advantage. One can fairly ask
what the army’s decision would have been if the regime had waited a few weeks
before ordering a severe repression.
4.2 The importance of uncertainty and beliefs in the Tunisian transition
The army believed that the results of the protests were too uncertain to
take a step forward and act against Ben Ali’s regime. This paper argues that,
on January 12th 2011, the militaries were better-off to refuse Ben Ali’s order
to open fire at the demonstrators and, by doing so, they brought a decisive
“coup” to change the regime in place, i.e. its preferred outcome. More
precisely, the balance of power on the
field at that time was such that the probability of having a new regime in
place was likely, even with the army on the regime’s side. Therefore the army
believed that its action to back the population would make the transition
almost certain. Also, the risk to shoot at
protesters was too high as the potential new government would have punished
them harshly. Thus the army was determinant in ending the long-term equilibrium
built by the regime over a quarter of a century.
Considering this paper’s results, Ben Ali’s regime would have been
better-off to keep the status quo instead of ordering a repression led by the
army. The regime miscalculated its army’s interest because of asymmetry of
information. It is not argued here that
Ben Ali would have stayed in power if the status quo had remained. Instead, it
is likely that the regime would have stayed much longer in place while the
security apparatus, excluding the army, were fighting protesters in the
streets.
In addition to that, there is high uncertainty that the army would have
backed the population if the status quo had remained. The cost of protesting is
increasingly higher over time for the
demonstrators because it is not affordable financially, physically and
psychologically. Therefore, the likelihood that Ben Ali stays in power was
increasing over time and the army may not have backed the population as it did,
because of too an uncertain balance of power on the field.
Therefore, it is demonstrated here that beliefs, asymmetry of information
and timing played a central role in the Tunisian regime transition.
4.3 Refusing an order as a strong signal and commitment device
The army’s decision to refuse to shoot at demonstrators triggered strong
signals to the population and Ben Ali’s foreign supports. The following
arguments help to understand why the Tunisian regime collapsed in barely one
month.
First, the army’s decision to reject Ben Ali’s order was seen as a strong
signal by the population. It signaled to the population the current weakness of
Ben Ali’s power, the division between elites and therefore, that the
dictatorship is potentially close to break down. Demonstrations may have shown
the true nature of the regime by providing a cascade of information, as
described by Lohmann (1994). While demonstrations multiply interactions between
Tunisian citizens, this has also been reinforced by the
predominance of social media. The army’s refusal to repress the
demonstrators was a key information that spread quickly in Tunisia. Protesters
received this signal that ended their illusion concerning the regime’s real
power. Demonstrators’ beliefs are likely to have considerably changed after the
army took position against Ben Ali’s regime repression.
Second, the army had no choice but to commit to its position of backing
the population. After the army took the side of the demonstrators, the army had
to take actions to foster Ben Ali’s fall. The army directly suggested Ben Ali
to leave the country temporarily until the situation cools down. In the Art of
War, Sun Zu mentioned such strategic actions to not “burn bridges” to give the
enemies the opportunity to leave the battlefield and thus not commit until the
end. The army’s decision to not burn bridges to Ben Ali is crucial to
understand the rapidity of the Tunisian transition. In fact, Ben Ali was given
an opportunity to leave the country immediately instead of fighting to defend
his power. Ben Ali had no choice but to
stay on the Tunisian territory, he would have been committed to fight
until the end, similarly to Qaddafi’s bloodbath in Libya. However, it is
believed here that this new and immediate opportunity changed Ben Ali’s payoffs
to stay in power and resulted in his departure to Saudi Arabia on 14 January
2011.
Third, the army’s decision to support protesters was also a strong signal
send to Ben Ali’s foreign allies. Because the threat that Ben Ali will fall
became credible, foreign allies, notably western countries, could not been
associated with Ben Ali’s dictatorship
and against democratic movements. The provision of weapons by foreign allies
became all of sudden very risky for two reasons. First, foreign allies would
hurt their reputation by backing a falling and authoritarian regime. Second, a
potentially post-Ben Ali era is unpredictable and lethal weapons may end up in
the wrong ends, especially in a country located so close to Western Europe.
Instead a few Arab countries, especially countries from the Gulf region, saw in
Ben Ali’s departure an opportunity to advance their influence and their
ideology in the country. Overall, foreign allies would not back Ben Ali’s
regime after the army’s desertion. Ben Ali’s power was weak and ending. It
became too risky for allies to consistently back the falling regime.
4.4. Implications in the post-regime change period
In the post-Ben Ali’s departure, we are now interested in how Tunisia
managed this period. After democratic elections in October 2011, the Islamic
Party Al-Nahda was elected to run the country and write a new constitution with
the consent of opposition parties. However a political crisis arose when two
opposition leaders, Mohamed Brahmi and Chokri Belaid, were assassinated.
Massive protests arose once again and political and societal instability
prevailed for at least a year (Sprusansky, 2014). The main task of the army
forces in the transition period was to fight terrorists in the mountainous
region of Tunisia. Military generals did not show any political ambitions to
take over the country despite high political instability. The fact that it
became an apolitical force without any economic interest in the country can
explain his non- inference in public affairs. Despite the relative division of
the Tunisian society between pro- and anti-Al Nahda, Tunisian people took
advantage of the newly obtained freedom of expression to debate and exchange
their ideas and opinions. Although a few incidents arose during the
transitions, a civil war was never expected because the armed forces were
highly independent from the political arena. Way (2011) didn’t show optimistic views
on the Tunisian transition because of the weakness of democratic forces.
However, he gave too much importance on the political parties and undermined
the role of the Labor Union in Tunisia. In fact, the relative smooth political
transition was managed by the Tunisian General
Labor Union (UGTT). This labor organization was used to bring political
actors on the
negotiation table in order to end the political crisis and finish the
redaction of the new Tunisian constitution, voted with a large majority on
January 27th, 2014.
V. Conclusion
Despite the Tunisian army’s lack of involvement in the political and
institutional sphere, this article concludes that it has changed the rules of
the game in the political transition in Tunisia.
The recent literature on Tunisia has mostly focused on the role of
popular mobilization. It must be emphasized that we do not neglect the role of
the Tunisian population. However, we argue that the army’s decision to reject
Ben Ali’s order to shoot at the population has been pivotal and has generated
very strong signals to key actors that changed their beliefs about the
evolution and the outcomes of the popular protests. It is true that some
articles have seen that the role of the militaries was crucial to explain Ben Ali’s departure, but
their analysis have been more descriptive than explanatory.
Instead the extended game introduced here enables us to see what type of
interactions, strategies and outcomes influenced the army’s decision. Bayles
and Lo (2012) rightly thought that uncertainty is key in regime transition and,
for this reason, it is taken into account here as well.
More research is needed on business power in Tunisia and how this had
influenced the Tunisian transition. It
is true that Trabelsi’s family (the President’s wife family) have multiplied
unconventional behaviors before the 2011 uprising, such as imposing the bank or
businesses to give (“lend”) them money. However, it would be crucial to know to
what extend businesses discontent is related to the army’s decision to reject
Ben Ali’s regime order, by researching how business and military elites has
interacted pre-transition.
VI. References
Aleya-Sghaier A. (2012). “The
Tunisian Revolution: The Revolution of Dignity”,
Journal
of the Middle East and Africa.
Allal
Amin and Vincent Geisser (2012). “TUNISIE : “Revolution de Jasmin ou
Intifada?”, La Découverte | Mouvements.
Anderson, L. (2011). ”Demystifying the Arab Spring Parsing the
Differences Between Tunisia, Egypt, and Libya”, Foreign Affairs. 3 Apr. 2011. Web. 22 Apr. 2014. http://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/67693/lisa-
anderson/demystifying-the-arab-spring.
Badie, B (2011). “Printemps arabe
: un commencement”, Etudes, 7 Tome
415, 7-18.
Barany Z. (2012). “Comparing the Arab Revolts, the role of the military”,
Journal of Democracy, October 2011,
Vol 22, Issue 4, pp 24-35.
BBC News Middle East. “Tunisian army chief dies in air crash”, Retrieved
1 May2002 from
http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/world/middle_east/1962415.stm
Bellin, E. (2004). “The Robustness of Authoritarianism in the Middle
East: Exceptionalism in Comparative Perspective”, Comparative Politics, Vol. 36, No. 2 (Jan., 2004), pp. 139-157.
Bellin E. (2012). “Reconsidering the Robustness of Authoritarianism in
the Middle East, Lessons from the Arab Spring”, Comparative Politics, Vol. 44, No. 2,
(Jan., 2012), pp. 127-149(23).
Blaydes, L., and Lo, J. (2011). “One man, one vote, one time? A model of
democratization in the Middle East”, Journal
of Theoretical Politics 2012 24: 110 originally published online 14
November 2011.
Campante
F. R. and Chor D (2012). “Why was the Arab World Poised for Revolution?
Schooling, Economic Opportunities, and theArab Spring”, The Journal of Economic Perspectives.
Cavatorta,
F (2012). “Le printemps arabe : le réveil de la société civile. Aperçu
general”. Barcelone: Institut Européen de
la Méditerranée (IEMed).
Cloutier, J-D. (2012). “Mobilisations populaires et changements
politiques en Afrique du Nord: Une analyse du « Printemps arabe » en Égypte et
Tunisie”.
Unpublished Ph.D. thesis,
University of Ottawa.
Dalacoura K. (2012). “The 2011 uprisings in the Arab Middle East:
political change and geopolitical implications”, International Affairs, 88: 1 (2012) 63–79.
El-Khawas M.A. (2012). “Tunisia’s
Jasmine Revolution: Causes and Impact”,
Mediterranean
Quarterly, Duke University Press.
Gause G. (2011). “Why Middle East Studies Missed the Arab Spring, The
Myth of Authoritarian Stability”, Foreign
Affairs, 1 July 2011. Web. 22 Apr. 2014.
<http://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/67932/f-gregory-gause-iii/why-
middle-east-studies-missed-the-arab-spring>.
Hess S. (2013). “From the Arab Spring to the Chinese Winter: The
institutional sources of authoritarian vulnerability and resilience in Egypt,
Tunisia, and China”, International
Political Science Review, 0(0) 1–19.
Beatrice Hibou (2006). “The Force of Obedience: The Political Economy of
Repression in Tunisia”. Polity. June
2011.
IISS
(International Institute for Strategic Studies) (2010). “The Military Balance
2009-2010”. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Illan R.W. (2012). “Tunisia and the Critical Legal Theory of Dissensus”, Law Critique.
Jdey
A. (2012). “A History of Tunisia, January 14, 2011: The End of a Dictator and
the Beginning of Democratic Construction”, Boundary
2 Duke University Press Journals
Joffe G. (2011). “The Arab Spring in North Africa: origins and
prospects”, The Journal of North African
Studies.
Kuhn R. (2012). “On the Role of
Human Development in the Arab Spring”,
Population and
Development Review.
Leventoglu, Bahar (2013). “Social
Mobility, Middle Class, and Political Transitions”,
forthcoming in
Journal of Conflict Resolution.
Lohmann, S. (1994). "The Dynamics of Informational Cascades: the
Monday Demonstrations in Leipzig, East Germany, 1989-1991." World Politics (1994) 47: 42--101.
Murphy E. (2011). “The Tunisian
Uprising and the Precarious Path to Democracy”,
Mediterranean
Politics,
16(2), 299-305.
Przeworski,
A. (1991). “Democracy and the Market: Political and Economic Reforms in Eastern
Europe and Latin America”, Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Schraeder
P. (2012). “Tunisia’s Jasmine Revolution, International Intervention, and
Popular Sovereignty”, The Whitehead
Journal of Diplomacy and International Relations.
Schraeder
P. and Redissi H (2011). “Ben Ali’s Fall”, Journal
of Democracy, 22.3 : 5 19.
Sorenson D. (2012). “Revisiting
Transitions in the Arab World, Spring or Fall?”,
ASPJ Africa &
Francophonie.
Sprusansky, D. (2014).
"Comparing national dialogues in Tunisia, Yemen and Libya",
The Washington report on Middle East affairs (8755-4917), 33 (1), p. 55.
Way, L. (2011). “Comparing the Arab Revolts: The Lessons of 1989”, Journal of Democracy 22 (no 4): 17-27.
VI. Appendix
Appendix 1. Features
of Arab Armies6
![]() |
Type of civil-
|
Economic
Power
Support
to
mobilization
Regime
Change
Tunisia
|
Autocratic officer-
politician regime
|
High
|
No
|
Yes
|
Yes
|
Egypt
|
Autocratic officer- politician
regime
|
Medium
|
Yes
|
Yes –
passive
|
Yes
|
Yemen
|
Autocratic officer- politician
regime
|
Very
low
|
No
|
Divided
|
Yes (relative)
|
Jordan
|
Tribally
dependent monarchy
|
Medium
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
Oman
|
Tribally
dependent monarchy
|
Low
|
Yes
|
No
|
No
|
Bahrain
|
Tribally
dependent monarchy
|
Low
|
Yes
|
No
|
No
|
Kuweit
|
Tribally
dependent monarchy
|
Low
|
Yes
|
No
|
No
|
Morrocco
|
Tribally
dependent monarchy
|
Low
|
No
|
No
|
No
|
Algeria
|
Autocratic officer- politician
regime
|
Low
|
Yes
|
No
|
No
|
Syria
|
Autocratic officer- politician
regime
|
Low
|
Yes
|
No
|
No
|
Lybia
|
Dual military regime
|
Very low:
fragmented military
|
Yes
|
No
|
No
|
![]() |